Featured post

Gender in the Merovingian World

Showing posts with label Anglo-Saxon armies. Show all posts
Showing posts with label Anglo-Saxon armies. Show all posts

Saturday, 7 May 2011

Warfare, the ‘State’ and Change around 600

[This is the text of a more specialist paper I presented at Vitoria, at the Universidad del Pais Vasco/Euskal Herriko Unibertsitatea, last Thursday. There are a number of typos that I'll try to weed out over the next few days.  For now, bear with me.  This is the latest incarnation of my general exploration of the nature of change around 600 especially as it concerns the issue of the 'State'.  I didn't have enough time in the paper to talk about this in more detail; perhaps I will compose something separate for the blog, that you can all pick apart.  In the meantime, I have tried to take on board the more important critiques and modifications suggested by its fairly disastrous Cambridge outing.  Essentially I try to argue for a profound change in the organisation of warfare and in its practice in the decades around 600, and then attempt to tie these developments together and to possible change in the nature of the post-imperial western European polities.  You will probably note particular confusion as regards the treatment of the Spanish data!]

Introduction
In this paper I will try and bring the results of research conducted some years ago, on warfare and society, together with a project on which I am currently working on, on the important changes that took place in western Europe between the last third of the sixth century and the first half of the seventh, for which I have used the shorthand ‘The Transformations’ of the Year 600’. It does not represent a final, fully-formed thesis, even insofar as my own work ever does. What I present is the current stage of a work in progress, one that has seen me change my mind more than once, especially about the state, and therefore I am very interested to hear what your responses are. One reason why I think that the changes that took place around 600 have not been given the attention they deserve is the fracturing of European history from the grand narrative of the Roman Empire, its growth, its decline and its fall – whatever one might think of that narrative – into a series of regional or national historiographical traditions and master-narratives. With this in mind it is especially important for me to hear the responses from a different national historiographical tradition to what I have to say.

My paper has two aspects. One is the establishment of profound changes in the practice and organisation of warfare, and the other is the impact of these changes on the nature of post-imperial polities. In particular, the discussion confronts the issue of whether western European kingdoms after circa 600 can still be referred to as states, or whether what is at stake is rather a crucial change in the nature or type of states they were. The other issue concerns whether or not what we can see in this period in the West is the end of the Roman world, not as a political entity but as a set of beliefs, a world view. This relates to the first problem, of political change, in that it addresses the issue of hegemony, in the sense of the word that was used by Antonio Gramsci. If the Roman world view changed, and if the legitimacy of the state – its hegemony – was related to this world view, how did western politics respond in order to maintain the dominance of large areas. We should not forget that the post-imperial kingdoms held larger areas together than any of the realms that succeeded them, up to the early modern period at least. This is a point that makes these discussions even more important. My paper then is about whether we can see what we might very loosely call a ‘military revolution’ around 600, whether we can detect changes in the nature of the early medieval polity and the way it maintained authority and consent within its territory, and whether and how, if we can establish these two points, they are related.

Post-imperial armies
The armies of the fifth and sixth centuries emerged from the last armies of the western Empire. The latter were rather different from the familiar fourth-century Roman army, but were clearly a development from those forces.

For most of the fourth century the Roman army was a standard regular standing force. It differed from the armies of the early empire in that the old differentiation between legionaries and auxiliaries had been replaced by a new hierarchy, which broadly speaking passed from troops stationed on the frontiers – limitanei – through legions upgraded from that status to serve in the field armies – pseudocomitatenses – to the comitatenses, the field army troops. This uppermost tier was itself subdivided into the praesental field armies – those ‘in the presence’ of the emperor – and more regional field armies. Within the field armies an élite was represented by the palatine regiments, the auxilia palatina especially, and the imperial guards regiments, the scholae. Pay and conditions varied according to where one stood within this hierarchy. For some time it has occasionally been argued that an imperial Grand Strategy existed: a defence in depth wherein the limitanei existed to deal with small localised threats and to delay more serious incursions, until the field armies could move up and defeat the invaders. This idea has been pretty thoroughly discredited in almost all its aspects.

The regiments of the auxilia palatina are especially interesting for my purposes. They were recruited initially, it seems, in the period of the Tetrarchy. Constantine I is often associated with their establishment, and damned for doing so by pagan writers like Zosimus who thought that he had started the end of the Empire by introducing these barbarians. This is especially interesting as it is an accusation directly analogous to that thrown at Theodosius and his sons by hostile writers for recruiting large numbers of Goths. I’ll return to this.

During the early fourth century the civil bureaucracy was separated from the military, as part of the Tetrarchic reforms aimed at reducing the risk of rebellion. The old style of education – paideia – remained crucial to advancement and status within the civil service and so this part of the imperial service seems to have appropriated most of the old ideas of Roman civic masculinity, moderation, the control of emotions, and so on. This, I argued in my book on Barbarian Migrations left the army to create its own set of identities, and these were based around things which were the antithesis of the traditional civic Roman male: barbarians and animals. One can see this by looking at the names of the regiments of the auxilia palatina. These are not simply based on contemporary barbarian groups, from whom, presumably, the regiment was initially recruited: Franks, Saxons, Sarmatians, etc. These regiments demonstrably kept their ethnic title long after they stopped being recruited from the barbarians in question – and this was not a new situation, as has been shown with reference to regiments of ‘Moorish’ light cavalry. They also include barbarian groups from the Roman past: Celts, Sabines, Parthians and so on. One doubts that these regiments were recruited from the people in question… Other regiments have names that have a boasting character, quite different from the names of early Roman Legions, some of which have distinct barbarian undertones, such as the regiments of the Feroces (Fierce Ones). Finally there are regiments named after animals: bullocks and lions. This creates, overall, a set of images quite antithetical to the controlled, rational civic Roman.

This was only part of the creation of barbarised identities in the fourth-century field-army. The costume of the late Roman army had clear barbarian features in its trousers and cloaks – which were demonstrably worn by officers of Roman origin. Words of non-Roman origin became accepted as standard military terms within the army. As the century progressed, officers of Germanic extraction, rather than adopting Roman names, increasingly kept their barbarian name. Overall, although there were many actual barbarians in the ranks, the barbarian identities adopted by the Roman army were, I argued, more a Roman artefact, created from traditional Roman ethnography.

The army, furthermore, had its own jurisdictions. Soldiers were exempt from various taxes, especially on the land they were given on discharge, which was frequently drawn from the Empire’s stock of agri deserti, lands for which no designated tax-payer appeared on the tax-lists. The military profession was, hereditary, as the story of Saint Martin makes clear.

Around the end of the fourth century, the empire began to pay its servants, civil and military via a process of the delegation of taxes to designated individuals. The precise mechanisms are difficult to unravel, in particular whether individual soldiers collected their pay directly from specified tax-payers or whether this was done on the basis of the regiment. Whatever the case, on occasion the soldier could leave his delegatio to his heirs. So, by around 400, we have a situation wherein Romans, including aristocrats, were accustomed to serving in units with barbarian names, alongside barbarians, dressing in barbarian costume and using non-Roman military language.

The next stage in the development was the introduction of the foederati after the battle of Adrianople. Traditionally, these have been thought to have been barbarian irregulars recruited from Goths settled as quasi-autonomous groups within the Empire, but a close examination of the data suggests that this was not the case and that what the foederati were were regular units of a new sort, recruited from barbarians, principally Goths. Within a generation, it is clear that these new élite formations were following the same pattern as the auxilia palatina a century earlier. Olympiodorus tells us that they were composed of people of all sorts. By the sixth century, in the eastern empire, Procopius informs us that a foederatus, while he had once been a barbarian in a treaty relationship with the Empire, was now simply a member of a regiment of foederati, and in Maurice’s Strategikon the foederati are simply élite regular cavalry.

In the west such a development was curtailed by the political fragmentation and civil war of the fifth century. In the political circumstances of the period, various regional factions, of Roman aristocrats and armies largely composed of and led by barbarians did not have the resources to tax and raise armies from limited territories under insecure control. Troops were therefore recruited from non-Romans, or the descendants of such; most of the great ‘barbarians’ of fifth-century politics were actually born and bred inside the Roman Empire. It’s worth remembering that. The model of the late fourth century was extended. Barbarian soldiers continued to be paid either through the delegation of tax revenue, as Walter Goffart has suggested, or sometimes through their settlement on the fringes of the territory under political control. Land was found for them on their retirement, probably, as before, from agri deserti. Also, as before, far from all of these ‘barbarian’ soldiers were actual barbarians even by descent. Romans – that is Romans not even claiming a barbarian identity – could and did hold military commands in Gaul, Spain and Italy.

None of this was especially new or shocking. Romans were already used to ‘barbarian armies’, and indeed to serving in them. The ethnic identity of the armies was only, in many ways, an extension of the earlier situation seen with the auxilia palatina regiments and with those of the Gothic foederati. Soldiers with their own legal codes, with their own non-Roman identities, with tax-exemption on their lands, with hereditary service: all this was familiar from the fourth century. The situation had simply been developed and extended. In the economic contraction of the fifth century, it may be that salary was drawn more in kind, and that a closer relationship between soldier and designated tax-payer developed. It may well be that the relationship envisaged by delegatio became more fixed and more hierarchical but on balance the armies that we can trace in the sources of the later fifth and sixth centuries, though quite unlike the regular armies of the fourth century, are nevertheless a clear development from them.

This model describes and explains the armies that are visible to us in the very late fifth and sixth centuries throughout most of western Europe. In Merovingian Gaul or Francia, armies seem to have been organised by civitas. In the north it seems that they were raised from these units by royal officials, the counts, dukes and their subordinates, from landowners claiming a Frankish identity. The military aristocracy could be referred to as ‘the Franks’ and the pactus legis salicae sets out what seem to be two parallel free hierarchies, one Roman and relating to tax-paying and perhaps civil administration and one Frankish and more related to the army. The Franks also considered themselves exempt from certain forms of taxation, leading to some riots and reprisals when kings attempted to tax them. I have suggested that they were raised from these units by royal officials, the counts, dukes and their subordinates, from landowners claiming a Frankish identity. The military aristocracy could be referred to as ‘the Franks’ and the pactus legis salicae sets out what seem to be two parallel free hierarchies, one Roman and relating to tax-paying and perhaps civil administration and one Frankish and more related to the army. The Franks also considered themselves exempt from certain forms of taxation, leading to some riots and reprisals when kings attempted to tax them. I have suggested (although obviously this cannot be proven) that the root of the problem was that Franks considered themselves exempt from all tax on land, whereas kings only considered the lands they held in return for their military service as exempt from these levies. In Aquitaine, after the expulsion of the Goths in the early sixth century, although at the same time probably continuing a situation that existed there under the Goths, it is clear that Gallo-Roman aristocrats led armies and that armies were raised from these people. With no substantial Frankish settlement and the removal of the Goths, perhaps there was no alternative to this. A story in Gregory of Tours’ Histories suggests a division into landowners liable to military service and tenants who were not. Otherwise the civitas-based mechanism for raising the army is well-attested.

A similar bipartite organisation is visible, as is well-known, in Ostrogothic Italy. There it is possible that we can see similar geographical variations, in areas away from the initial settlement of the Ostrogoths, and a shift through time as Romans acquired military roles and perhaps started to adopt Gothic identity, although this process was cut short by the Gothic Wars. The Goths – the army – seem to have been paid in the delegation of tax revenue, as Goffart suggested, although they were also granted lands and these may have been exempt from taxation. The regular assemblies of the Goths were occasions wherein the kings could distribute and redistribute their patronage and expose their military followers to statements of royal ideology. I suspect a similar usage by the Franks of their assemblies of the Marchfield on 1 March. The evidence is less plentiful from earlier Visigothic Spain but insofar as it can be evaluated it suggests, on balance a similar organisation.

Territorial levies of certain types of landowner – Franks or Goths – were supplemented by the military households of the kings and their principal aristocrats, and these in many ways functioned as a sort of standing army, although one must be careful to make clear that in many important regards this was only true in certain restricted senses of the term. The terms bucellarius, antrustio, saio, gardingus, and puer can all be found being used to describe these more professional warriors. Age and position in the life-cycle seem to have played an important role in the recruitment to these groups, as the term puer indicates. What seems to have been the case is that young, unmarried males served their military apprenticeship in one of these households. If such service was performed well then it seems that they would receive lands and so on, marry and settle down. It might even be that the military ethnicity was acquired at this stage, as there are no references in the pactus legis salicae to any Frankish children – only adults have an ethnic identity. Clearly details varied. In Spain, bucellarii could keep any weapons given them for life but any land they were given remained in the dominium of their masters. Which stage of a military career is envisaged by this law is not, however, entirely clear. As far as we can tell, and the waters are muddied by that fact that sometimes the detailed information only comes after the period I am looking at in this section, those warriors of the royal household referred to as the antrustiones, the gardingi or the gasindi in Lombard Italy all seem to be an older category of established and experienced warriors. These would seem to be warriors with their own households, perhaps in more intermittent attendance on the king than the younger pueri regis. This might itself have been a continuation of Roman practice. After all, the imperial bodyguards, the scholae have given their name to ‘schools’ and the schola palatina is a term that one encounters in sources about the Merovingian palace and its military elements. Similarly, it might be – although several theories have been proposed – that the division of Roman regiments in iuniores and seniores is related to age. In many ways it might be the simplest explanation although strangely it has rarely been suggested.

In terms of weaponry, the armies of this period similarly appear to represent developments of late Roman practice. The archaeological record seems, from Anglo-Saxon England south to the more Mediterranean regions, to give an impression of warfare based at least partly on mobility and fluidity. Such analysis as there is suggests a predominance of weapons suitable for throwing and/or shooting, such as franciscae, angones, javelins and so on, alongside shield-bosses that similarly suggest a mobile form of fighting. They are designed, it seems to catch and parry blades in a fencing style of fighting. These weapons are found alongside weaponry for close-in fighting but overall a tactical practice that was not dissimilar to that, as far as it can be established, of the late Roman army does not seem implausible, with volleys of missile weapons before hand-to-hand-fighting. 

Armies and the State (1)
In terms of its relationship to the government of the realm, though, it can be concluded that, across the post-imperial West, the army served as an instrument of royal power. In the situation following the disintegration of the western Empire, the kings held all the aces in their relationships with an aristocracy which, in some areas, such as Britain and northern Gaul, needed royal service and patronage as the best means of maintaining any sort of local social pre-eminence and, in others such as Spain, southern Gaul and Italy, needed this sort of favour in order to maintain the sort of active involvement in large-scale politics to which it had become accustomed under the Empire, and to maintain its position within its peer group. The more established Roman senatorial aristocracies of places like Aquitaine and Italy were increasingly driven to seek royal office, and indeed to seek roles with a military command, as their local political dominance was threatened as the kings introduced their own followers – their Franks or Goths – as their agents into regional society and politics. Such officials had greater de facto power because of their military command and their direct link to the king, however much greater the ancestral and cultural standing, or landholding wealth, of the old Roman nobility might have been. Thus aristocrats who were potentially capable of dominating and indeed governing their regions were bound into the Merovingian state by their participation in the competition for the favours, patronage and offices bestowed by the Frankish kings. Aquitaine remained firmly a part of the Frankish kingdom without kings ever having to go there. Compare that with the situation in the ninth century. As a result of these royal policies, the army could be, and was, used as a coercive force by the kings against rebellious aristocrats.

I suspect that similar dynamics were at play in the Ostrogothic kingdom. Areas close to Theoderic’s capitals in the north probably functioned much like the northern regions of the Frankish kingdom. Areas further away probably saw similar dynamics to those visible in Aquitaine.

An alternative situation is visible in Spain, and this might partly explain why the evidence is less clear even than that from Gaul. The royal dynasty of the Visigoths was extinguished by a Frank called Besso in 532. The last king of the line, Amalaric, had not reigned in his own right for very long; before that the realm was under the not unsuccessful leadership of the Ostrogothic general Theudis. The crisis of 507-10, the expulsion from Gaul and the minority of Amalaric that followed came not very long after the start of the kingdom of Toulouse’s expansion into Spain. Not only that, but possibly fairly successful, though temporary and badly documented, campaigning continued in Gaul until the 530s. Gregory of Tours lets slip that the Goths retook much of the territory lost to Clovis, these campaigns of reconquest presumably being led by Theudis. All of these features probably explain why the Gothic kingdom in Iberia should I think not be seen as a kingdom covering all of the peninsula outside the control of the Suevic realm of the north-west but as little more than a loose hegemony outside a band of directly-controlled territory extending from the north-east, around Barcelona, through to perhaps Mérida. The crisis of Agila’s reign was produced by a defeat at the hands of the citizens of Cordoba, and similar, evidently city- or local senate-based polities appear in the sources for Leuvigild’s reign – they had, I assume, always been there. It is, in my opinion, not coincidental that the distribution of furnished burials, and especially of burials with weapons, lies around the fringes of this kingdom, where rival bases for local power might have been in competition.

In other words, the failure of the Goths to create a dynasty with the hegemony created by the Merovingians in Gaul, or to wield, before Leuvigild, the sort of military force necessary to bring the peripheral regions into the realm, local aristocrats saw no reason to incorporate their regions within the Gothic kingdom. This might be one reason why Theudis maintained his authority with an army raised from the private estates of his Hispano-Roman wife. Michael Kulikowski has plausibly suggested that such forces in the fifth century were used as a counter-point to the forces of the cities and I suspect that this might have been the case for Theudis in the sixth century too, although doubtless he also had to confront the possibly centrifugal forces of rival Gothic aristocrats and their own forces.

Within the areas controlled by the Visigothic kings it seems to be the case that the Gothic army was a similar sort of royal force to that we can see in Gaul. However, the clearer evidence in support of this view comes with Leuvigild’s reign. I suggest that it was the case that Leuvigild’s military successes functioned much as similar military successes had done with the Merovingians two or three generations previously, allowing him to eradicate alternative regional and local sources of authority. Military success allowed him to reduce potentially rival noble dynasties to a status closer to that of service aristocrats, using the same sorts of mechanisms as in early Merovingian Gaul: the distribution and redistribution of patronage, the insertion of royal officials with military backing into local politics and so on. Of course, the curse of the Visigoths after 532, that none of their dynasties managed to survive more than two generations, nipped this development in the bud with Reccared’s death in 602.

A not entirely dissimilar set of factors explains the fragmentation of post-Justinianic Italy after the Lombard invasion, at least until the early eighth century.

Description of change
We can now move on to the changes that occurred around the year 600. Note, however, that the situation in western Europe in the later fifth and sixth centuries was certainly not without its dynamism and regional variation. I will describe the changes that I think took place under the same general headings as I used in the previous section, first looking at the mechanisms of raising armies and then looking at what we can say about armament, strategy and tactics.

The principal aspect of change in military service can be summed up, I think, by calling it a move towards armies composed of aristocratic retinues. Now, some words of clarification are necessary to at least imply that some nuance underlies what must of necessity in a short lecture appear to be crude generalisations. For one thing, retinues had played a big part in the royal armies of the fifth and sixth centuries, as I have already described – the pueri, the bucellarii and the rest. It is also likely that at least the wealthier Franks and Goths summoned to the army by royal officials came with their own pueri in attendance, even if only to fetch and carry. The distinction I would like to suggest is that in the sixth century the aristocrats whose military households formed the core of armies held their position principally as royal officials, and kings could and did remove them from these positions. What happened to their retinues in such circumstances is undocumented but one imagines that much of it transferred to the new incumbent. I wonder if considerations relating to this lie behind Visigothic law’s distinction between gifts of weapons and of land to bucellarii.

Similarly, and related to this point, the means by which the army was called became, I suggest, more selective according to wealth and status. This again requires clarification. I do not suggest that the sixth-century levy was unselective. To have called out every Frank or every landowner within a civitas would very likely have produced more men than were either needed or could practically be fed and supported on campaign. So, especially as Frankish ethnicity spread in northern Gaul, the counts, dukes and centenarii, I imagine, selected the best equipped and the most locally politically powerful, influential and well-connected men in the region. This and the point about retinues are important to spell out as I do not think that I made these points clear enough in my previous writing on the subject.

The fifth- and sixth-century situation had contained within it the seeds of change. One was the common ethnic nature of military service. Ethnicity was not fixed and might have been something acquired at about the age where a male established a household. Further, unsurprisingly, it appears to have been gendered in the immediately post-imperial period: ethnic identities are ascribed overwhelmingly to men. However, the attractions of non-Roman ethnicity inevitably meant that it became steadily more common and, by 600, more or less universal among the aristocracy and free landholding classes across most of the West. Simultaneously, it appears to have been more universally assigned within families of such ethnicity (to children and women as well as adult males). Given the tax-exemption of people subject to military service, this development will have meant that liability for duty in the army, and one presumes a concomitant inclusion within their ranks, spread to freemen less able to bear the costs of such service. It will also have reduced the amount of land subject to royal taxation and, through the inheritance of ‘military lands’ by women of non-Roman ethnicity, probably led to its tenure by people considered incapable of performing military service. These points alone would probably have produced significant change in the raising of armies there were many other factors that made the decades around 600 a period of intense transformation of western European society and economy. Another key development in many regions was a growth in the power of aristocracies, vis-à-vis the monarchs. Thus significant changes in the nature of armies during the seventh century are unsurprising.

By the mid-seventh century it is very difficult to see any trace of the post-imperial means of raising armies. Mentions of the ‘men of Mainz’ and of the pagenses of Saintes in a campaign of 639 may be the last allusions to levies based on the old administrative districts (the civitates and pagi), such as had been common in the sixth century. Instead, references to armies take us in two complimentary directions. On the one hand we begin to encounter what might be termed ‘select’ levies – scarae. The word is cognate with the English words ‘shear’ and ‘share’ and implies a select band, cut (or sheared) off from the mass. With the presumed spread of liability for military service (if assessed according to ethnic identity) this is unsurprising; a levy of the free population would be entirely impractical. In the social and economic context of the early middle ages, armies larger than a few thousand men were unfeasible. It is here that the term ‘select’ should be qualified as above. What changed between the sixth and the seventh century was not whether or not warriors were drawn from a select group but the means of selecting such troops.

How this ‘shearing’ was carried out is suggested by the other prevailing aspect of seventh-century military organisation: the aristocratic retinue. With the words of caution made above, we can nevertheless say that military households dominated seventh-century army-composition. Their precise nature also appears to have changed. Seventh-century sources widely acknowledge the existence of freemen dependent upon their more powerful fellows, and a class of aristocrats whose power was (unlike in the sixth century) quite independent of royal service. Evidence of more secure tenure of large estates by such magnates is more easily found and these lands were used to reward followers. This seems to have meant that, whereas in the sixth century the older warrior performed his military service to the king according to general systems of obligation, in the seventh, even after leaving the age-group of the pueri, the warrior still performed military service in his lord’s retinue. In diverse parts of western Europe such nobles appear to have interposed themselves between the king and the remainder of the free population. Around 600 the last vestiges of Roman taxation disappeared, largely because these imposts had passed into the control of estate owners. We find legislation concerned with the frequent intrusion of magnates into the operation of royal justice, protecting their ‘satellites’ from the sentence of judges. At the same time, aristocratic dynasties become more visible, frequently monopolising administrative offices whose bestowal had hitherto been entirely within the royal gift. We are as yet some way from the situation where counties or duchies were hereditary but the detectable sequences of counts in particular areas from the same families strongly suggest that, although such a title had no value without the legitimation of royal appointment, these kin-groups had a clear expectation that the king would appoint one of their members when the post became vacant.

Juxtaposing these general developments, it seems that during the seventh century the magnates were able to insert themselves into the means of levying the army. When a military force was required, even if legitimised by royal summons and nominally employing old ideas of liability for military service, in practice the local counts would select or ‘shear off’, from all those theoretically liable for military service, the most politically and socially important land-holders and their allies and dependents. As the army was the most important political assembly within a kingdom (see below), the choice of whom to summon and whom to leave behind was a significant source of local power and patronage. What happened in most of the seventh-century West might, then, not unreasonably be termed a ‘privatisation’ of the army. I have distinguished the different means of levying an army by the terms ‘horizontal’ (levied according to a kingdom-wide ‘flat rate’ by royal agents working within specific royal administrative districts: the sixth-century model) and ‘vertical’ (raised down chains of dependence within aristocratic estates and dependencies as in the seventh century); this may yet suffice as a crude short-hand.

Intriguingly, a significant change in armament seems to have occurred at this time. The practice of burying weapons in graves provides, by early medieval standards, an enormous sample (many thousands of items) of contemporary weaponry, although unevenly distributed geographically and temporally. Between c.575 and c.625, several hitherto common items disappear from that record. In Francia especially, these include the francisca and the ango. In England, certain types of javelin also cease to be found. Simultaneously, a change in defensive weaponry occurs. In the seventh century, shields became larger, with longer and heavier bosses, perhaps more suited simply to shoving or punching an enemy. Contemporary with these changes, the sword becomes less frequent in the record while the one-edged dagger (scramasax) becomes longer, broader and weightier. Spearheads also became larger and heavier. It is risky to deduce a shift in tactics from a change in weaponry but the transformation of armament between c.575 and c.625 seems to point in one general direction: from a faster, more open, type of warfare with small, easily mobile shields and much use of specialised missile weapons towards combat centred on close-packed hand-to-hand fighting. The larger, heavier shields and spears seem adapted to this type of warfare and the broad, chopping, single-edged scramasax is more suited to it than the two-edged broadsword. Indeed the scramasax combines the best features of the sword and battle axe, the latter of which (like the throwing axe) disappears from the record until the Viking era.

Surviving evidence provides no real clues as to whether defensive armour became more common, as one might expect. Helmets and body-armour are proportionately more frequent in the seventh century than the sixth but we cannot deduce much from this. The burial of armour was geographically very restricted, and cannot reflect its actual frequency. It was probably more affected by ritual demands than the burial of other items. Furthermore, outside southern Germany most surviving examples come from entirely untypical burials (the ship burials at Sutton Hoo in East Anglia and at Vendel and Valsgärde in Sweden).

Relating developments in armament and the putative tactical change deduced from them to the transformation in the raising of armies is difficult. Some of the weaponry which dropped out of use – especially the francisca – apparently required specialist training to use effectively, whereas one might, superficially, wonder whether close-fighting ‘shield-wall’ tactics were more suitable to larger, comparatively less well-trained forces. However, as noted, seventh-century armies were perhaps no more select than sixth-century; the means of selection changed. Further, and this might be crucial, close-fighting techniques probably required more expensive protective equipment, notably helmets and body-armour, which could have restricted participation to those with the economic wherewithal to provide protection for themselves and their followers. This would tally with the growth of aristocratic power discussed above. It is also possible that the coherent employment of close-fighting techniques required the elements of a ‘shield-wall’ to have more frequent training as a body. This might be more feasible within an aristocratic retinue than in an irregularly assembled conglomeration of land-owners. However, this can only remain a suggestion and there are arguments that one might present in opposition to it.

In much of north-western Europe the period from c.600 onwards was one of economic expansion, which might well have enabled slightly larger armies to be mobilised, at least for large-scale conflict. This and the increased private resources in the hands of local aristocrats could also support a growth in the frequency of metal body-armour. It might also have been more feasible for aristocrats to equip larger followings with probably the most expensive item of a warrior’s equipment, his horse. However likely this might seem from the period’s general economic developments, and although there are some indications of this in the data, an increase in the proportion of an army’s mounted troops is as impossible to confirm from our evidence as a growth in the frequency of armour and helmets. As with the other suggestions linking social and military developments in the period after 600, it might nevertheless be worth retaining as a working hypothesis.

Armies and ‘the ‘state’ (2)
There are two ways of thinking about the question of the state from the perspective of these changes. We might call ‘the weak thesis’ the idea that this period saw the demise simply of a particular ideal sub-type: the ‘late antique state’. ‘The strong thesis’ would be the idea that what happened represented the end of anything that can reasonably be called a state with any analytical precision, in the late antique west. .

The idea that anything that could helpfully be called a state ended in around 600 in western Europe is historiographically unfashionable. Recent historiography has tended to rehabilitate the notion of an early medieval state. This is, to no small degree, linked to the rise of what is called the ‘consensus model’ of early medieval politics, which argues that political negotiation and the use of royal ritual created the consensus necessary to keep aristocrats in league with the kings and indeed get anything done. The idea of a zero-sum model of politics, wherein a growth in aristocratic power equals a commensurate reduction of royal power (or vice versa), has seriously been questioned. More fashionable is the idea that kings and aristocrats worked together in mutually beneficial fashion. A growth in the power of one can lead to a growth in the power of the other: constantly increasing the total amount of power, if you like. Good historians have shown convincingly that early medieval people had an idea of a political community that existed outside the persons who happened to rule in particular ways at particular times and places. Even the most un-state-like of early medieval realms existed on the basis of more than mere personal links. All this has shown us that cohesive kingdoms existed in the early Middle Ages and this has been elided into the idea that therefore such polities were states. In 2003, in Warfare and Society in the Barbarian West, I talked willy-nilly about coherent kingdoms as ‘states’.

But cohesion, to me, does not equate quite with statehood. The more recent impressive ‘statist’ historiography does not seem to me to have made the case for thinking of the early medieval realm as a state, in an analytically useful fashion. No one has explained the demise of the late Roman bureaucratic state in the west, and the Roman state did end. No one has produced a reliable and/or theoretically coherent ‘worked example’ showing exactly how aristocrats and kings worked together to maximise the power and authority available to each in the early Middle Ages. Although the zero-sum model may not have existed in its crude form, I do think that something very like it did exist. In other words, the acquisition of certain types of power by local or regional aristocracies did mean a relative diminution of the effectiveness of central government. When all power, ultimately, comes from the land, there is really no way of avoiding this point.

Similarly, the flaws of the approach are pointed up if you look at ‘horizontal’ as well as ‘vertical’ competition, that is to say competition within the strata of the élite classes as well as between them. If, in the words of one fairly recent (if unreliable) writer on the topic bluntly says, ‘the struggle for political power was not a zero sum game’, why was there a struggle at all? And indeed the consensus, statist model of the early medieval state usually appears to be pretty struggle-free. Most papers on the topic say at some point that ‘we should not assume that this was a cosy state of affairs’ but, if one continues to read, one rarely gets the impression that this state of affairs was anything but cosy.

And yet, these were polities where kings blinded their own sons, where civil wars broke out that occasionally at least resulted in fairly bloody battles. So what, if everyone gained, were they fighting, killing and dying over?

There are three main problems with the current historical trend in favour of the early medieval state. First, all the work upon ‘buying in’, upon consensus, has moved us too far away from coercion, from the radiating out. For a state to exist meaningfully both have to be present. A state must be able actively to penetrate local and regional society from above as well as to persuade local and regional élites to invest in it from below. Local aristocrats and others might have used the legitimacy of power provided by involvement in the structures of a realm to further their own ends, creating the coherence of that realm as a political entity. But what if any chance did rulers have of enforcing compliance with his wishes in the localities? The former state of affairs suggests a coherent kingdom but only if we can answer the latter question with evidence of at least relatively effective evidence that kings to had the ability coerce their aristocrats in cases where they did not wish to comply are we in the presence of a state.

The second, closely related, problem is that historians of all perspectives, Marxist or otherwise, have assumed an alliance between local élites, or aristocracies, and central government, kings, emperors or whatever. This alliance has never been shown to be necessary. Indeed I think the assumption is fundamentally mistaken.

The third problem is that the appreciation of collective power has come at the expense of a neglect of what Mann called distributive power: power which, if more is accumulated in the hands of one person or group, involves a decrease in the power of another. As Mann argues, both types of power exist simultaneously; we are not talking about a crude zero-sum game.

In an early medieval context, there is an important materialist challenge to the concentration upon ideology and collective power. The period that concerns me (and indeed most of the early medieval period in the West) was one where power ultimately resided in the control of land and its surplus. Most of it was non-monetary and, on either side of the 600 watershed, there were few truly urban centres. Trade and commerce were in any comparative sense, rudimentary, in spite of the wealth of very good work done in recent decades on unravelling such exchange systems and networks. Certain types of power might have been collective and potentially infinite, but the material basis of power was finite. Seed-yield ratios may have been less bad than used to be thought but there was still a fairly clear limit on the surplus to be drawn from land, and it was never entirely secure, as the incidence of famine shows. Technology limited surplus extraction to muscle power, human and animal – again finite. And the amount of land available was – also – finite. Thus whatever the ideological and other investments in effective power, when you come down to the basics, the resources of power were limited.

There is a very basic – indeed a brutal – implication of all this. In a socio-economic situation such as existed in western Europe after the break-up of the Roman Empire, armed forces could only be maintained by and rewarded with land and/or the revenues or surpluses from land. Thus armed force, which, like agricultural techniques in this period, was a simple question of human and animal muscle, was a fixed resource. Control over armed force, over the military source of power, was, ultimately, therefore distributive.

A polity whose rulers do not tax and thus have no income derived other than from their position as simply one élite landholder among many, and who have no effective independent coercive force, cannot, in my vaguely Weberian view, be called a state.

This talk requires definitions. Most discussions of the state, since Weber, have continues to turn on the issue of force. The first of Chris Wickham’s defining characteristics is ‘The centralization of legitimate enforceable authority (justice and the army)’. Susan Reynolds modifies Weber’s monopoly of force to a control of legitimate force. Michael Mann also stresses the control of coercive force.

One would not consider a state that had no means of enforcing its rule other than via violence against its subjects to be a very secure state – it might today be called a failed or failing state. And yet a state that has no ability, beyond persuasion, to penetrate a barrier of local aristocrats to ensure that its writ runs in local society does not seem to me to be much of a state either. Nor do I think it is helpful at all, as Susan Reynolds does, to think that a polity that is a loose confederation of small, tightly controlled lordships should be called a collection of mini-states. One must have a control of legitimacy, to be sure, but the branding of some actions as legitimate and others as not, can be an empty gesture without the ability to penalise the illegitimate. To my mind the rulers of kingdoms like the Merovingian demonstrably had the ability to penalise the illegitimate as a matter of course, in a way that their successors would find increasingly difficult. So there must be an ideology of legitimacy that works in convincing local and regional élites to work for the state, and indeed which places (as in many definitions of states) the power derived from state function higher than the power derived from de facto local wealth and social distinction. Such things have been very well studied. However, comparative study of political dynamics across late antiquity, the middle ages and beyond shows that for us to be able to discuss a polity as a state, those means of persuasion, the establishment of a monopoly of legitimate power must, at some stage be based around the idea to back up followers and reduce opponents through force. This does not seem to me to be out of step with Chris Wickham’s or Susan Reynolds’ general definitions of what it takes to be a state. Where I disagree with Chris is that I think that the western European kingdoms before 600 fit his definition as states, whereas those afterwards, increasingly do not.

Conclusion
Thus, alongside the general continuation of taxation, the ability of rulers between 400 and 600 to summon and employ a coercive military force allows us to think of their kingdoms as ‘states’. With the change in the raising of armies just described, this situation altered profoundly. From c.600, the mustering of armies was increasingly (with temporal and geographical exceptions) a matter of negotiation between the royal court and local and regional aristocracies. This in turn meant that in practice it was concomitantly difficult for a monarch to summon an army to resolve internal difficulties such as recalcitrant or rebellious noblemen. The army ceased to be classifiable as an independent governmental coercive force, which must have profoundly affected kings’ ability to harness the surplus of their realms beyond their own private estates. Thus, against historiographical fashion, I think that this makes it unjustifiable to classify as states the kingdoms of the period after c.600. None of this, it cannot be emphasised too strongly, implies that these polities were not cohesive or that kings did not wield considerable authority. Dynastic legitimacy and other ideological strategies could mean that the royal court remained the essential focus of politics. Nevertheless, without the ability to raise armed forces independently of regional and local magnates in order to impose their will upon the diverse localities of their realms, it is unhelpful to call these kingdoms states. Doubtless this version of what I called the ‘strong thesis’ still requires more subtlety and reflection, but I think that something profoundly happened to late antique states in western Europe around 600, and I continue (just about) to think that what happened was that they ceased to be states.

Warfare and society in the early medieval West

[This is the text of a general lecture that I gave at the Universitad del Pais Vasco/Euskal Herriko Unibertsitatea in Vitoria last Wednesday.  To anyone who knows anything about the subject, I cannot promise anything new or surprising; to anyone else I hope it might be a useful sort of introduction and overview.  Essentially, after a brief historiography, I try to relate the practice of warfare to its important role in society and politics.]


Introduction
One of the most common images in the popular idea of the early middle ages – the dark ages as they are still often called in the UK – is of violence and warfare: in the UK the image of invading barbarians or Vikings, pillaging and plundering Roman Britain or the Christian kingdoms; in this part of the world the constant warfare of Christian and Muslim; the warrior, king or aristocrat, clad in mail and carrying his great sword. It is certainly not my intention in this lecture to argue that this picture is mistaken! Warfare was common in the early Middle Ages, and possibly more common even than our sources suggest. What I want to discuss instead is why this period saw so much warfare, and why this was a not a symptom of mindless barbarism and violence. Warfare played a very important part in early medieval society and politics but because of this it was often limited in scale.

The first point I want to make is to ask – very briefly – how we define warfare, and peace. And how early medieval people did. There were many levels of violence in the early medieval world, and sometime these were quite clearly defined according to the law – or at least the law tried to define them. An eighth-century Anglo-Saxon law famously defines the different activities of thieves, of a ‘band’ and of an army according to the number of men involved. There was a similar attempt to differentiate between private warfare between nobles (which was called werra, from which we get most modern European vernacular words for war) and that of the king – ‘public’ warfare – which was referred to a by the Latin term bellum in Carolingian Francia. Christian penitentials also sometimes differentiated between killing in public warfare and killing done in the course of private disputes.

Mostly, however, the differentiation was fairly blurred between what we might think of war today – official, large-scale conflict between different political units – and the levels of violence below such as border-raiding. A series of treaties exists that were signed between the doges of Venice and the Carolingian rulers of Italy, which makes it clear that there was a constant ‘background noise’ of cattle rustling and other cross-border raiding that the rulers of the two side agreed to try and prevent. It seems that this sort of thing, which an Iberian audience can readily envisage in the usually imagery of Christian/Muslim raiding across the border, went on most of the time and was only stopped (in theory) at exceptional moments. Overall it seems that in the early medieval way of seeing war and peace was the opposite of the modern western way. It was peace that was the exceptional state of affairs that required formal marking through legal activities. Some level of what would now be considered warfare appears to have been a constant across almost all frontiers. Why this should have been the case is something that will concern me later on in my lecture.

Historiography
There have been a number of traditional ways of seeing early medieval warfare. Probably the oldest, perhaps finding its most famous proponent in the prolific English historian Sir Charles Oman, was to see early medieval warfare as essentially mindless barbaric ravaging, a sorry decline from the scientific warfare of the Romans, only be rectified with the reappearance of military science in the renaissance. That this was not the case has long been established, not least by J.F. Verbruggen, but there are still some problems in the perception of early medieval warfare.

Most of these, I suggest, stem from not taking early medieval warfare on its own terms and trying to force it into a different framework, which it won’t fit. One of the most prolifically maintained, has been the attempt by one American professor to argue for a complete continuity of ‘Vegetian’ Roman warfare, regular armies and the social and economic structures of the early Roman period which maintained them. He has famously argued that early medieval armies numbered many tens of thousands of men, perhaps up to 100,000 men under arms at one time, though not necessarily all in the same army. The fact that the economy of the early middle ages could never have supported such enormous concentrations of manpower – indeed nor could that of the late Roman Empire, or late medieval and early modern states up to at least the eighteenth century – is what has led him more recently to move his arguments onto attempts to maintain that the Roman socio-economic system continued with no break at all into the middle ages, to the ninth century and beyond – in the teeth of decades of sophisticated archaeological work showing the opposite to be the case.

Fortunately, though, these ideas have been little heeded by scholars with any subtle understanding of the period, but they need to be referred to for the simple fact that in quantitative terms they rather dominate recent historical writing on the topic. A rebuttal of the thesis need not take long. There is no written evidence of any sort which documents the survival of any sort of regular, paid ‘standing army’ in the usually understood sense, anywhere in western Europe outside areas controlled by the Byzantine Empire or, later the Umayyad emirate, later Caliphate, of Cordoba. There was serious economic decline in north-western Europe in the fifth and sixth centuries and slightly later in the more southerly, Mediterranean regions. An important period of change, which I will refer to later on in this lecture and which I will be discussing in greater detail in another lecture, tomorrow, broke most of the direct links between the later Merovingian ad Carolingian worlds and the late Roman Empire, so that very few areas of direct continuity can be identified. Even after the economic upturn of the seventh century, in the north-west, the economic and social structures of western Europe could not support large armies. If pressed I should say that, before the ninth century, large armies probably tended to number in the region of 5,000 men. After that forces of 10,000 may have been practical on occasion but one doubts that such forces were maintained as single armies for any length of time. In some areas of Europe – Ireland and northern Britain for example – one would think that armies were smaller throughout the period that concerns me.

At the same time, though, the arguments that numbered early medieval armies in hundreds or even fewer can also be rejected. Mostly these are derived from a misunderstanding of some legal sources. Some raiding forces might have been of this order of size, however. Ultimately, however, the only honest answer would be that we do not know how big early medieval armies were. The point I would like to stress is that the size of armies probably varied not simply according to time and place within the early medieval world but also according to the type of warfare that was being waged. As I will suggest later on, early medieval warfare came in several forms and scales, with their own particular practices.

Similarly, the ‘equal-and-opposite’ argument to the ultra Romanist continuity argument, that this was a period of ‘Germanic’ barbarian warfare, is also to be rejected. This is manifested in extreme form in a recent book by Michael Speidel (otherwise, perhaps ironically, a respected scholar on the imperial Roman army). This is a position that, equally, can only be maintain by a set of very forced and uncritical readings of the material. The debate over Roman versus barbarian clouds the issue. A recent encyclopaedia entry on the subject obscures the issue further rather than elucidating it. It states that, for me, Roman warfare was already ‘barbarian’ before the end of the Roman Empire. This is nonsense; certainly I have never argued that at all, or even seen the debate in these terms.

There was continuity from the late Roman Empire on into the post-imperial world in some important senses, but this was neither a straight prolongation of the late imperial Roman army nor a ‘barbarisation’ of Roman warfare. It is a simple matter of constant and dynamic change. The Roman army evolved in the course of the fifth century, within the frameworks that were established in the fourth century. It continued a process of what we might call ‘barbarisation’ but we must be very careful about what we mean by that term. I have been very careful to clarify that this was an issue of the Roman army adopting what it thought were martial barbarian identities and practices – in opposition to the civic Roman identity appropriated by the now separate civil service – but that these were very much rooted within the traditions of Roman ethnography. They were not genuine features imported wholesale from barbaricum. The actual practice of warfare did not change very noticeably.

We can detect an evolution, during the fifth century, from the regular Roman army of the fourth century into the ‘ethnic’ armies of the fifth and sixth centuries, but this is not to be understood as the impact of tribal barbarian societies on the western Empire. Service in the later fourth-century Roman army was inherited from father to son – a hereditary occupation – at least in theory. The Roman army had its own separate legal jurisdiction. I have just said that it had adopted a number of what it considered to be barbarian customs, costumes and identities. Many regiments bore the name of barbarian groups but they were quickly recruited from all sorts of people. A sixth-century Egyptian papyrus records a violent ‘police action’ by a group of ‘Franks’ billeted in the area. These ‘Franks’ are very unlikely indeed to have been actual Frankish recruits from Gaul; what is much more likely to have been the case is that they were members of the regiment of ‘Franks’ stationed in Egypt since about 300 AD. More than two centuries later these, by now solidly Egyptian troops still called themselves ‘Franks’. This is a very important case study. At the very end of the fourth century, furthermore, the Empire began to pay its troops (and civil servants) through the ‘delegation’ (delegatio) of tax revenue to the army. In other words, tax payers paid a section of their tax directly to designated soldiers. Whether tis was done on an individual or a regimental basis is unclear. In some circumstances these delegationes could be inherited by a soldier’s heirs. This came hand in hand with a certain tax exemption, which also applied to certain lands owned by soldiers, not least the lands they were given on discharge, often drawn from the agri deserti (deserted fields), for which no tax-payer was registered.

If you put all of these elements together you get a picture rather like that which we can detect in later fifth and sixth-century sources. By this date, in the west, armies were raised from people of a particular ethnic identity, usually barbarian, probably but not necessarily an inherited status. These warriors had their own laws – the so-called barbarian codes – they held lands which were exempt from taxation. Indeed there seems to have been a separation into ‘barbarian’ soldiers and ‘Roman’ taxpayers that perpetuated the Roman situation. How this situation evolved from the one I just described is not difficult to understand in the political situation of the fifth century wherein different regional factions competed for authority but rarely controlled enough territory to be able to raise large sums in tax or recruit large armies, and thus relied ever more on recruits drawn from ‘barbarian’ groups – although it is worth remembering that most of these barbarians had been born and had grown up inside the Roman Empire. Talking about all this as an issue of Roman continuity or new barbarian methods entirely – as I see it – misses the point. This was neither the take-over of western Europe by immigrant barbarian military societies with new social and military practices and nor was it – evidently – a simple continuation of the Roman regular army. It was an evolution that took place within the particular, distinct circumstances of the fifth and sixth centuries.

This general point, about seeing early medieval warfare in its own terms, applies to another common view of the period, which would understands it by extending the observed features of central and later medieval warfare backwards into our era. Thus it is sometimes said that battles were rare in this period. They were risky and therefore they were not generally sought. Instead sieges were the most important feature of warfare. This is, as far as I can see, a reasonable description of warfare in the age of castles and knights, from the eleventh century, perhaps the tenth, through to the end of the Middle Ages, but, as I will argue later, it is quite mistaken for the period between the sixth century and the ninth.

The final historical trend that I want to mention is that which sees the early medieval; ‘barbarian west’ as an ‘heroic age’. In Britain this is a notion most famously associated with Hector Munro Chadwick. Based on certain written sources like the poetry, it is claimed that this era had important things in common with Homeric Greece. To my mind, this misunderstands the nature of these heavily stereotypical sources, which in many cases appear to be harking back to an earlier ‘golden age’ that had in fact never existed, or which created a personalised depiction of warfare from a very impersonal means of fighting. Again, I will return to this point later on.

Role in society and politics
Warfare manifested its social importance particularly strongly in the sphere of kingship. This was not new. Third- and fourth-century Roman emperors had been expected to be competent war-leaders, especially against barbarians. There may have been some input from barbaricum. However, as far as we can detect them, by the end of the fourth century barbarian ideas of rule and power were so saturated with Roman influences that it is impossible to find any distinctive features in the evidence we have, without going back to the writings of Caesar and Tacitus. Barbarian society had, however, changed considerably between the time when they wrote and the late imperial period. The distinctive features of early medieval kingship should be understood, again, as new developments rather than hammered into the categories of either ‘Roman’ or ‘barbarian’. That said, it was very often the case that success or failure in warfare was even more crucial in the early medieval period than during the late Roman Empire. In the history of the Iberian Peninsula, a couple of sixth-century examples will illustrate the point. King Theudis was assassinated after a defeat during an invasion of Byzantine North Africa. King Agila was faced by rebellion and usurpation after an attempt to impose a more effective rule over Cordoba resulted in a defeat for his army. Very often it was a matter of contemporaries’ perception of success and the ability to enact the ideals of kingship that counted, rather than actual military performance as it can be analysed by modern historians. So the military policies of the emperor Charles III, Charles ‘the Fat’, in the ninth century can be seen today as simply continuing the general lines of Carolingian policy towards the Vikings, without very much of a decline in their fortunes. However, Charles failed to live up to what was expected of him, especially in the political circumstances of his reign. This can be seen in the sources for his reign, which are very hostile towards him. At the same time, the count of Paris, Odo, was leading what some contemporaries regarded as an heroic defence of the city against a Viking siege which Charles spectacularly failed to raise. Odo could therefore be presented as doing what a king should have been doing, and Charles as derelict in his royal duty. Within a year or so, as a result, Charles was indeed deposed. The list of early medieval rulers whose power fragmented, often fatally, as a result of defeat in battle is a very long one.

The principal exception to this is the Merovingian dynasty at the height of its power in the second half of the sixth century. Although kings did lead armies on occasion and had frequently served as commanders for their fathers, which might have served to establish their military credentials, reigning monarchs very rarely put themselves at the head of their armed forces. Such was their power and dominance of Frankish politics that they were able to appropriate the credit from the successes of their generals and on the whole avoid the fall-out from their armies’ defeats, which were quite frequent, especially in attempts to invade Visigothic and Lombard territory. This changed at the very end of the sixth century, when Merovingian monarchs began once again to lead their armies in person.

One reason why this might have been the case concerns the relationships between the Merovingian kings and their aristocracy. In the decades around 600 the Frankish aristocracy in the north of Gaul appears to have consolidated and strengthened its local power in ways that made it much less dependent upon royal favour and patronage, making it less of a service aristocracy. One outcome of this, and something I will be talking more about tomorrow, was that the army appears to have started to be much more of a conglomeration of aristocratic revenues than a force raised on royal orders by royal officers. In this context it is perhaps to be expected that Frankish kings needed once again to demonstrate their military credentials.

This raises the point that military service had become essential for involvement in politics. One of the Frankish kings who led his armies personally in this period – indeed he even seems to have accompanied his army on a campaign to Italy when he was thirteen – was Childebert II of Austrasia. Childebert issued three edicts during his reign, or at least three that survive. All are dated on 1 March. That was the date of the Marchfield, the annual assembly of the army – in itself a sort of continuation of the Roman campus martius. It was not the only time that Frankish armies were called out or assembled – far from it – but it does seem to have acquired a particular political importance. In the sixth century, assemblies like this were used by kings, not just in Francia, to bestow gifts, reward and recognise good service, punish bad service, redistribute their patronage and expose their troops to royal ideology. What Childebert’s decrees make clear is that these assemblies were used for the promulgation of laws, and the perhaps merely ritual obtaining of the consensus of the powerful magnates of the realm. We can trace this right across the early medieval world. When the Lombard kings – in my reading at any rate – established a more effective royal control over their kingdom at the end of the seventh century and in the early eighth, they too issued their laws on 1 March at assemblies of their magnates and freemen – whom, significantly, they called arimanni or exercitales – ‘army-men’.

By the Carolingian period, the idea of the ruler obtaining the consent of his magnates had become even more important and many royal decisions, grants, laws were issued in the presence of the kingdom’s nobility. A charter of the Anglo-Saxon king Ecgberht, although of dubious authenticity, claims to have been issued when the king marched against the Britons, in 825. An Italian law of 863 specifies the duties of all free men as military service, maintenance of bridges and attendance at the law-courts. The connection between armed service and the law is often made clear in Italy, where a piece of Lombard legislation requires the freemen who come to court to attend with spear, shield and horse.

With all this said, it should not be surprising that the principal characteristic of the early medieval secular aristocrat were, from the seventh century onwards, almost exclusively military. In the Roma period, of course, there had been different forms of service, civic and military. In the early Empire, civil servants could hold military command, as when provincial governors led the troops within their jurisdictions, so the two forms of service could be fused. From the fourth century onwards, though the process doubtless began under the less well documented third-century emperors, the two forms of imperial service began to be clearly distinguished. Certain levels of Roman aristocratic society were banned from military command, civic administrative units became separate from military ones – often the two did not directly overlap. I have already mentioned that one outcome of this was the concentration of traditional ideas of Roman civic masculinity within the civil bureaucracy whereas the army adopted its own consciously non-Roman identities. Nonetheless the two career paths shared many things in common and both had the same, parallel levels of reward in prestige and privilege. It was during the fifth and sixth centuries that the martial model, the one associated with barbarian identity, came to be dominant so that aristocrats with the martial, barbarian ethnicity were, in Frankish Gaul, valued at twice the wergild as their civic ‘Roman’ counterparts.

Unsurprisingly, by the seventh century, the martial model had come to dominate the situation completely. Generally, civic forms of service had disappeared or the military officials had come to take over formerly civic responsibilities within their jurisdictions. The principal, soon the only, exception to this, was the Church, which perhaps not coincidentally, became the repository of many of the Roman ideas of civic virtue, such as moderation, the control of the emotions and so on. And yet it is clear that some, perhaps many, Churchmen in the early part of my period found this exclusion from military activity something of a problem. By the eighth and ninth century, as is well-known, churchmen were regularly to be found within the armies of Carolingian kings and their contemporaries, leading contingents raised from their estates and often armed and participating in battles. Lupus of Ferrères, a ninth-century abbot, complained that he wasn’t very good with sword and shield, but it seems clear that he was nevertheless expected to be able to wield them if need be.

The right to participate in warfare was very important in defining a number of social identities in the early medieval West – not just royal and aristocratic. One reason for this was that warfare was a very specific form of violence and weapon-bearing. Anecdotal evidence from the early medieval West suggests that all sorts of people could or, in practice, did take part in low levels of violence – kidnappings, attacks, revenge-killings and so on. When weaponry was used as a symbol of identity, therefore, it is not simply the right to carry weapons that is at stake. It is the right to bear weapons in a particular context, that of warfare and the army. This was possible because the raising of armies was a deliberate and formal process, with clear points at which the selection of who could and who could not attend the muster. This remained true throughout the period, whether one is discussing the levying of all the Franks within a Gallic civitas in the sixth century, or the raising of land-owners according to the system of adiutorium in the ninth. The right to fight (and therefore to take part in high politics) was always a highly regulated process, and it is this, rather than their cost in labour and materials, that probably explains why weapons are so valuable in sources like the seventh-century Lex Ribvaria.

Several other dimensions of identity were linked to this deliberate process of selection. The first - ethnicity - has been touched upon already. In the fifth and sixth centuries, as I have mentioned, one of the means by which one proclaimed and maintained a claimed ‘barbarian identity – Frankish in Gaul, Gothic in Italy or Spain, probably Lombard in Italy – was through performance of military service in the army. One process that went hand in hand with the spread of this politico-military ethnicity was the gradual disappearance of a high-status civic aristocracy, and the reduction in many parts of Europe, of ‘Romans’ to a level of semi-free second-class citizens. By the seventh century the secular aristocracy, and indeed the bulk of the free population, in northern Gaul were all ‘Franks’, just as they had become Goths in Spain, Lombards in Italy and, for the most part, Angles or Saxons in lowland Britain.

Probably the most significant areas where this general rule was not the case was in the south-west of Gaul, in Aquitaine, where actual Frankish settlement was limited and where a high-status, prestigious Roman identity remained, even though this had become as martial as aristocratic identity anywhere else. In this part of the world it seems that military service was related to land-holding from an early date. What is interesting, and perhaps especially to an audience in Vittoria, is that in the later seventh century the ties which bound Frankish polity loosened importantly so that the south, like some other parts of Merovingian hegemony, became semi-detached from the northern core of the realm. It acquired its own line of dukes, well known from the history of the eighth century, and these ended up involved in a long armed struggle against the northern Pippinid or Carolingian mayors of the Palace, eventually kings of the Franks. It is in the course of this struggle that one sees the spread of the term Vasconia eventually to become Gascony – the land of the Vascones or Basques – to describe Aquitaine, not just the land south of the Garonne. In my interpretation, what this means is a process similar to that which had happened in the north a couple of centuries previously. Military conflicts between the Merovingians and the Basques of the Pyrenees are attested in the sixth century and of course these remained fairly common right through the period that concerns me, up to the second great Frankish defeat at Roncesvalles in the 820s. In the late seventh and eighth centuries, rather than an actual spread of settlement and political domination in those terms, what seems to me to have been the case was that the Basques had come to form the most valuable elements, the cutting edge, of Aquitanian armies. As a result of that a Basque identity became important in politics, just as Frankish identity had done in the sixth-century north. In the wars against Charles Martel and his successors, this Basque identity was especially important in providing an alternative to the Frankishness of the northerners. Had Eudo and Waifar won their wars perhaps the south-west of France would permanently have become Vasconia - ‘Basque-land’ - into the late Middle Ages and beyond. As it was, the victory of the Franks ended this development, and the Carolingians promoted a regional Aquitanian identity instead.

Masculinity itself to some extent was bound up with military service, at least among certain groups, be these defined by wealth and/or birth, such as the aristocracy or groups based on ethnic identity. The masculine symbols par excellence in many of the furnished cemeteries of the early part of my period are weapons, as will be discussed in other lectures this week. It’s worth stating that these weapons are not mere symbols. Although they are full of symbolism, that symbolism is linked to a very direct and contemporary military resonance. As I have said, more than once, the sword worn by an early medieval aristocrat, depicted on wall-paintings, placed in burials and so on, is not the ceremonial sword of the British Knights of the Garter – a symbol of status and of a past history – but much more like the AK47 brandished by the rebel or the warlord in all troubled parts of the world. These were efficient killing instruments in which was invested a great deal of wealth and technology. In the secular world, as I have mentioned, such was the dominance of the martial model that not bearing weapons seems to have posed problems for other groups in society. In the early part of my period, the church repeatedly had to legislate against clerics bearing weapons. Presumably such individuals, churchmen or not, celibate or not, regarded themselves as somehow lesser men if they could not carry a sword. And, again as mentioned, by the eighth century, ecclesiastics had made their way into the ranks of the warriors.

The last identity that I want to discuss that is related to the performance of military service – again it cross-cuts those I have already mentioned (masculinity, class and ethnicity) – is that of age. One of the more interesting revelations of the study of sixth-century furnished cemeteries over the last couple of decades has been the ways in which age plays a role in determining the grave-goods placed with the dead. This varies greatly from region to region. In Frankish northern Gaul male children and adolescents were very rarely buried with weapons. The only exceptions to this rule are prestigious burials, whether on a local level or a national one, as with the famous ‘prince’ from Cologne. Only at the age of about twenty are males generally buried with weapons. This is interesting as superficially it contradicts the written evidence, which seems to refer to adolescents involved in violent and even military activities, and, on the other hand, marriage took place later for men. What might be at stake is a point at which a fully gendered identity is acquired – perhaps a full ethnic identity – after some years of apprenticeship. It might be that married heads of households were those buried with the fullest sets of weapons. This is certainly the case amongst the Alamans of south-western Germany. Differences can be noticed among the Anglo-Saxons, where male children are buried with spears, but there shields are also only acquired at about twenty and full weapon sets seem to gravitate towards mature adult males. This suggests interesting possibilities about how military service was moderated by age as well as the other dimensions of social organisation.

Strategy and Tactics
The more practical elements of military history – strategy and tactics – were heavily influenced by the social and political factors just discussed. Here we can return to one of the points I made at the start, that early medieval warfare must be understood in its own terms. It cannot be understood by assuming that the features of warfare that we can see when we start to get detailed information on the subject in the central middle ages also applied earlier on. Differences in the survival of evidence are often themselves brought about by changes in society and politics or by changes in mentalities. They cannot be explained entirely by chance. This makes it questionable to assume that a standard medieval set of characteristics defined warfare between the end of the western Roman Empire and the start of the Renaissance.

Something which has been argued to define medieval warfare is a lack of battles and a plethora of sieges. Battles were risky, as early medieval people knew. That much is true. In the central and later Middle Ages we can see that battles were not risked very often. Knights often took themselves to their castles, where they might withstand a siege. This, however, does not seem to have been the early medieval pattern, up to around the end of the ninth century at least. Examination of historical sources reveals that battles were relatively frequent. Seventh-century English history, for example, is littered with battles. No fewer than twenty-two are named in the sources. And, however big or small they were by comparison with warfare in other times and places, these were politically important events. Twelve of them are mentioned as producing the death of at least one king or other important leader.

Why did early medieval commanders commit themselves and their armies to the lottery of battle so frequently? Partly the answer lies in the broader social and economic context of the period. By comparison with the Roman period, or the central and later Middle Ages, much of the early medieval era in western Europe was not a time of economic prosperity. This is especially true of the fifth and sixth centuries in the northern half of the area under study, whereas economic decline set in slightly later in southern Gaul, Spain and Italy, during the seventh century. Even when the economy began to expand, as it did in the north from the end of the sixth or start of the seventh century, trade was conducted on a smaller scale than in the ancient period and towns, such as there were, were small. Study of the economy and the settlement pattern does not suggest that great amounts of booty were to be had through the sacking or plundering of regions, even in the economically most prosperous regions. This might be one region why fortification and siege warfare remained fairly undeveloped during most of my period. There was, simply enough, little to be defended and little to be gained through costly assaults. By contrast, it is clear that especially in the earlier parts of the era that interests me, people wore their wealth. Swords, scabbards, armour and helmets were ornately gilded and decorated. The Staffordshire Hoard, unearthed in the UK about two years ago, has recently shown this especially clearly. Warriors’ clothing, too, one imagines, demonstrated their wealth and prestige. The horses on which more or less all early medieval armies travelled, and from which most could fight too, at least on occasion, were expensive items as well. Across the period between the fifth century and the ninth, the price of horses remained fairly stable at about ten solidi, though sometimes the best steeds fetched twice this amount, or more. What this really meant is difficult to judge, given that the solidus was usually a unit of account rather than an actual coin, but people exchanged reasonably-sized parcels of land for horses. In addition, kings went on campaign with their treasuries, expensive tents and so on. Thus the best way to acquire the treasure that was essential to oil the cogs of early medieval politics was to find and defeat the enemy army in open battle. The relative wealth of settlements and of warriors, and the level of fortification of the former, is obviously the opposite of that which existed from the ninth century, and especially from the tenth century, onwards. Thus, I would argue, it is not very surprising that the relative importance of battle and sieges was the reverse too.

The other reason for the frequency of battle is to be found in the importance that warfare had in the establishment and maintenance of social and political identities, discussed in my previous section. With warfare the underpinning of so many important dimensions of social organisation, from kingship down, not simply the assembly of the army and departure on campaign but actual fighting. The way in which these things weighed heavily on early medieval commanders can be demonstrated by an early eighth-century Italian example. A Lombard army was confronted by a Slavic army which had fortified its camp at the top of a steep hill. A conversation between two of the Lombard leaders led to one accusing the other of cowardice. The offended aristocrat responded by charging up the hill towards the Slavs and challenging the other leader to accompany him, which he did. The rest of the army then followed their squabbling leaders because, in the words of Paul the Deacon, ‘they considered it shameful not to’. The result, predictably enough, was a catastrophic defeat for the Lombards. The duke of Friuli had to establish a charity home to bring up all the children orphaned in the disaster. Other examples can be added, including Frankish defeats at the hands of the Saxons in the 780s and by the Slaves in the 850s. In both cases needless battles were brought about by petty rivalries and jealousy within the Frankish command.

In terms of actual tactical practice, the main point that I would like to stress is flexibility. An early medieval warrior was expected to master a wide range of military skills. He was supposed to be able to fight on horseback and on foot; he was expected to be able to shoot a bow accurately or throw a javelin as well as be able to fight with spear, sword and shield in hand-to-hand fighting. With this in mind it is not surprising that formal divisions into cavalry and infantry and into skirmishers and line of battle troops are difficult to pin down, and have become the subject of unprofitable debates. The crucial part of most battles was the clash of closely-packed blocks of warriors, whether on horseback or on foot, and the side that lost would suffer badly in the ensuing rout. This characterises the warfare of Anglo-Saxons, Franks, Vikings and many other peoples, as far as we can tell. It was not the only way of fighting, however. The Basques, for example, at least when fighting in their own country, employed a more open, skirmishing style of fighting, with hit and run attacks. The Franks not regard this as a fair way to fight, especially when explaining their defeats at the hands of a people whom they did not really regard as a fully-fledged enemy. A similar fighting style seems to have been employed by the Bretons, often with similar success. One imagines that it was the normal means of fighting in the west and north of Britain and in Ireland.
Continuity and change
My last major section concerns the issue of continuity and change. In a brief lecture like this one can give the impression that warfare in the early medieval West was something static and unchanging. Indeed, there are some areas, such as battlefield tactics, where, to judge from the evidence we have, this might indeed have been the case. But it is indeed always difficult to tell whether or not the impression of stasis results from actual long-term continuity of practice or whether it stems instead from the highly standardised and formulaic descriptions of warfare that have come down to us. This is a problem that often besets the early medieval historian, whose sources are very often governed by the demands of genre and the influence of accepted models. Yet it is particularly acute for the study of warfare. Our sources are remarkably tacit on the subject of warfare, how it was waged, and what it was like. It is quite the opposite of the situation in classical Greece, for example, where a wide range of sources, of very varied type, describe all the most intimate and earthy details of warfare at all its levels. It is very difficult to know why early medieval sources are so reticent about discussing warfare, but the fact is that they are, and this can make it very hard to explore the conduct of wars in detail, especially in looking at areas of change.

Significant change certainly did not take place in military technology between the fifth and ninth centuries. At the end of the period that concerns me, a warrior would have been armed and armoured in much the same way as at the start. Developments in the production of swords, increases in the size and specialisation of war-horses, the introduction of specialised tactics for charging with the lance and new weaponry like the crossbow: all these took place after the end of my period.

The introduction of the stirrup has been the subject of much debate. Ninth-century illustrations continue to depict warriors who are not using stirrups, suggesting that the stirrup cannot have revolutionised warfare. We can no longer accept that the introduction of the stirrup led to an increase in the importance of cavalry. Mounted warriors possibly became more numerically important through time but, as I have just said, the formal distinction into infantry and cavalry is anachronistic for this period. There were warriors who were wealthy enough to own horses and there were warriors who were not. The former group would fight on foot if the occasion required. It was proposed that the stirrup permitted a swift cavalry charge, smashing through the enemy line, but this does not seem to be the case. The true, knightly charge seems to have been developed much later, in the eleventh century, and appears to have followed the development of a high saddle that could keep the knight fixed securely on his mount. This is not, however, to deny that the stirrup was important in early medieval warfare, but that its importance lies within the styles of fighting I have outlined. Stirrups enable easier mounting and dismounting, something that mattered in a style of fighting where warriors might dismount and fight on foot in the middle of a battle, as Byzantine tactical manuals complained in the sixth century and as Louis III’s troops did at the battle of Saucourt in the ninth. The stirrup also makes long periods of riding less tiring. Finally, although the charge may not have been made more effective, stirrups do allow a mounted warrior to strike downwards and to his sides more easily. Throwing spears from horseback might also have been made easier. All of these factors mattered in the sort of raiding warfare that dominated the early Middle Ages.

Traditionally, it has been argued that the Arab invasions and conquest of Spain in the eighth century brought about a major change in western warfare. The argument was that the Arabs introduced fast-moving mounted warfare that compelled the Franks to find means of furnishing large numbers of mounted warriors to counter these attacks. The Arabs were thought to have used mounted archery and other skirmishing tactics that required new responses. None of this seems to have been the case. Some of it stems from taking imagery from the later Crusades and applying it to the eighth and ninth centuries. Arab armies were composed of large numbers of dismounted warriors and their cavalry did not use generally bows from horseback. Furthermore, no such dramatic change in the numbers of horse-borne warriors can be seen in the eighth century. If the relative numbers of warriors with horses ever increased significantly then this took place long before the Arabs’ arrival in Spain. Overall, though, warfare against the Arab forces in Spain and elsewhere was not very different from that which took place around and across the frontiers between early medieval kingdoms across western Europe.

Mention of a possible increase in the numbers of horse-borne warriors leads me to discuss one period where significant change did take place. This will be the subject, in greater detail, of my lecture tomorrow, and it is the period around 600AD. I must be brief but in the period covering the last third of the sixth century and the first half of the seventh a significant shift in the way that armies were raised appears to have taken place. It was in this period that the post-imperial form of army that I described earlier – that is to say armies raised from landowners claiming a particular ethnic identity, with particular tax-exemptions, and raised from the kingdom’s administrative districts by royally-appointed officers – was replaced by armies raised essentially down chains of lordship and dependence. This of course remained the basic template for the raising of armies through the rest of the Middle Ages until the gradual introduction of regular royal standing armies at the very end of that period. There were exceptions of course, such as the Caliphate of Cordoba but armies that were agglomerations of the retinues of the king and his aristocrats were the norm and this form of army first developed in the early seventh century. At the same time, there were changes in the weapons used, at least in some areas. In Britain and the areas of Merovingian hegemony, weapons like the heavy javelin (ango) and the throwing axe (francisca) drop out of the archaeological record, as do some forms of light throwing spear in England. Spears became heavier and shields larger. The scramasax, a heavy, one-edged machete, became more common. The one-handed axe disappears from the warriors’ array of weaponry until the Viking Age, probably replaced by the scramasax. It is possible, although this cannot be proven, that armour and horses became more common too. Overall a change in the style of fighting seems to have taken place, although how this related to the changes in the way armies were raised is difficult to establish.

I have said very little about the most famous warriors of the early Middle Ages, the Vikings. This is partly because in their appearance, the raising of their armies and the general aims of their warfare, they did not differ much from their enemies. However, it does seem that the Vikings were an important catalyst in the nature of warfare. In that, from the 850s, their armies often campaigned all-year round, they changed the nature of campaigning. In the fact that they could be bought off, or hired, they reintroduced the concept of the mercenary, and indeed the commoditisation of the professional warrior and of violence, that had been largely absent in the West since the fifth century. Their fortification of their bases and their speed of movement led to a new phase of royal fortifications and to new means of attempting to harness military manpower to the service of the king – most successful in Anglo-Saxon England. It may well be that their tactics, adopted to negate their enemies’ superior cavalry, also led to an increase in the importance of dismounted warfare, the ‘shield-wall’ warfare that is familiar from Old English and Scandinavian poetry.

The last period of change that concerns me comes at the very end of my period and in many regards runs on from the changes introduced by the Vikings. Marc Bloch said long ago that one result of the Viking raids was the growth in the importance of local defence, and this still seems to be correct. In England this took the form of a network of royal fortresses, which became the hubs of increased royal power and a return to something like the sixth-century means of raising an army as an effective royal force. In mainland Europe, however, such defences became smaller and – to be crude – eventually private works, castles. This and other developments adverted to earlier make tenth-century warfare significantly different from that of the ninth century and earlier. We enter the more immediately recognisable world of ‘medieval’ warfare with its knights and castles.

Conclusions
Today I have sketched some of what seem to me to be the more important aspects to emerge from recent research on warfare in western Europe between the fifth and the ninth centuries. Many areas of this subject cannot be examined in any detail because of the nature of the written data. Nevertheless close, sophisticated study of that evidence has, as well as revealing why it cannot be used in the old ways, allowed new, more subtle ways into exploring the issues. Early medieval archaeology, in particular, has permitted us to open up the study of warfare, its role in social organisation and its effects. Although this has included much new descriptive data, above all the input of archaeology underlines that the best way of looking at warfare and society in the early medieval west is to start from the areas which we do know about, which is to say the wider social and economic context, and moving from there to make more informed hypotheses about the areas which we cannot know much about. By following this approach, there remains much to be done in furthering our knowledge of warfare and society in western Europe in the Early Middle Ages.